The only woman to win the Nobel Prize for Economics showed that democratic management of commons isn't just possible, but normal.
Image may be NSFW.
Clik here to view.
The market
fundamentalism of Hayek seems to dominate political discourse. Hayek,
the liberal free market Austrian economists, argued that state
planning would end in failure and only the market could promote
economic efficiency. This agenda seems, since Thatcher and Reagan, to
have swept the world but it is, of course false. Neo-liberals far
from reducing state intervention use the state to support
corporations. Privatization is about helping powerful firms and
market competition is no longer an issue. A good example is the
current transformation of the NHS into a cash cow for Virgin and US
health corporations. Neo-liberals promote corporate welfare and
monopoly. Elinor Ostrom is powerful ally for all those of us who want
to challenge that neo-liberal dogma and create people centred
cooperative economics.
Elinor Ostrom, who sadly died in 2012,
was the first and so far only women to win a Nobel Prize, strictly
speaking the Swedish bank prize, for economics. She was awarded it
for her work on commons, collective resources and collective communal
property. If we want a practical alternative (s) to privatisation she
helps in a number of ways.
First, she is one of very few
thinkers who gets us beyond market and state binaries. Her Nobel
lecture was entitled 'Beyond markets and states', while she was
neither a radical anti-statist nor an anti-capitalist, she believed
that a whole host of ways of running an economy were possible and
that all sorts of cooperative and diverse ways of owning property and
dealing with economics had the potential to work. The idea that the
market was a panacea, or, indeed, the state, was alien to her
thinking. This approach is a good way of challenging the neo-liberal
idea that only privatisation is permitted - popular democratic
control of the economy and society is at the centre of Ostrom's
work.
Second, her research showed that far from being tragic,
commons were possible. In her most important book Governing
the Commons,
she looked at real world examples of commons that had succeed and
others that had failed. She discovered that some commons such as the
grazing pastures at Torbel in Switzerland had worked very well for
over a thousand years. She looked at how Spanish farmers have shared
limited irrigation water – using the same formula for centuries,
she examined how for generations, fishing communities in West Africa
have divided up access to fish, to ensure that only a sustainable
number are ever caught... Cooperative ownership is thus an
alternative to private corporate control of resources. Her work on
commons is a powerful challenge to neo-liberal assumptions that
corporate ownership is the ideal because cooperation always tends to
fail.
Third, she helped to discover ground rules to make
commons work. Often we think in slogans and make broad ideological
statements. She in contrast looked in very great detail and what made
cooperation more likely. Her eight design features for a
well-functioning commons, cannot simply be applied to all forms of
collective cooperative ownership but provide a very good start for
helping us. For example, running a cooperative or commons, involves
constructing rules as to who does what, her assumption that the more
participation co-operators have in making the rules the more likely
they are to stick to them, is just one useful insight.
Fourth,
she reminds us that institutions and culture are important. We live
in the UK in society where hierarchy and market values are often
strong, it is thus likely to involve some serious work to construct
alternatives. We need to look at examples which have worked and
others which have failed, working hard intellectually and practically
to build alternatives. Alternatives to neo-liberalism are possible in
a society but practice will be needed to get them right.
Fifth,
Ostrom was overwhelming pragmatic. She focussed on practical problems
and how to solve them. Her interest in commons and indeed that of her
husband Vincent, an interesting thinker in his own right, came from a
particular dilemma. They were interested in the problems of
conserving West Basin, a body of water near Los Angeles. If too many
users including farmers took water from it, the water level would
fall, salt water would be sucked in from the Pacific and West Basin
would be ruined as a source of fresh water. You can't divide water
courses up and sell them, so a solution that involved diverse user
cooperating had to be achieved. It might be said that human beings
face a variety of challenges in creating economies and institutions
that work for mutual benefit, the Ostrom approach of seeing these
challenges as forms of problem solving is I feel very
helpful.
Sixth, while Ostrom was never identified with the
radical left or anti-capitalism, her ideas when examined are
extraordinarily radical. For example, long before it was fashionable
she was an intersectional thinker, she always worked for women and
diverse but excluded social groups. The idea that economics was
gender neutral did not fit with her work. Her own experience shaped
this approach.
Her mother was Protestant, her father Jewish. She was brought up as a Protestant, yet she remembers children shouting 'Jew' at her in the Sunday school playground,
‘I got circled in the schoolroom, out on the playground.’
'You
Jew! You Jew!' she recalled, her voice rising, imitating the
taunts.
‘Having that experience as a kid and being a woman, and
having that challenge as it has been at different times to be a
woman, I've got pretty good sympathy for people who are not
necessarily at the centre of civic appreciation.*
She faced an uphill battle as a women wanting to study economics and this reinforced her love of diversity and democratic self-governance. Ecological considerations were built into her work, she developed the concept of social-ecological systems and argued that ecological sustainability was essential. She was also a keen advocate of the seven generation rule, derived from indigenous Americans, noting:
‘indigenous people in this country had a way of thinking seven generations into the future. We need to do more thinking about seven generations into the future’
Ostrom, to summarize, showed that an alternative to purely private ownership were possible, she argued for diverse, democratic ownership and ecological sustainability, a long way from the narrow assumptions of mainstream economics. Above all, she used detailed research methods to investigate how we could do better. Her work is essential for helping us to move away from an economy that is based on top down instruction, inequality and corporate control. She was a pragmatic radical and we can all learn from her.
*(Leonard 2009) Quoted in Wall 2014